Jump to content

Wealth tax: Difference between revisions

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Content deleted Content added
Sjorv (talk | contribs)
m fixed type "taxs" in intro
I added some examples of implemented and proposed wealth taxes in Bolivia and the UK. Furthermore I provided some more theoretical and empirical arguments to the pros and cons of a wealth tax
Line 105: Line 105:


However, Belgium now re-introduced the annual tax on securities accounts law with some modifications in February 2021. The Belgian Parliament adopted the adjusted tax on securities accounts law applicable from 26 February 2021, with the first reference period ending on 30 September 2021. A solidarity tax of 0.15% is now applicable on securities accounts that reach or exceed €1,000,000 without regard to the number of accountholders, and the tax amount is limited to 10% of the difference between the taxable base and the threshold of €1,000,000.<ref>{{Cite web |title=Belgium re-introduces an annual tax on securities accounts |url=https://www.regnology.net/en/resources/news/belgium-re-introduces-an-annual-tax-on-securities-accounts/ |access-date=2023-04-20 |website=www.regnology.net |language=en}}</ref>
However, Belgium now re-introduced the annual tax on securities accounts law with some modifications in February 2021. The Belgian Parliament adopted the adjusted tax on securities accounts law applicable from 26 February 2021, with the first reference period ending on 30 September 2021. A solidarity tax of 0.15% is now applicable on securities accounts that reach or exceed €1,000,000 without regard to the number of accountholders, and the tax amount is limited to 10% of the difference between the taxable base and the threshold of €1,000,000.<ref>{{Cite web |title=Belgium re-introduces an annual tax on securities accounts |url=https://www.regnology.net/en/resources/news/belgium-re-introduces-an-annual-tax-on-securities-accounts/ |access-date=2023-04-20 |website=www.regnology.net |language=en}}</ref>

==== Bolivia ====
In December 2020, the Bolivian socialist government of President [[Luis Arce]] approved a wealth tax on resident and non-resident individuals with a net fortune of over 30 million Bolivian Boliviano. The tax is progressive with tax rates in the range of 1.4% to 2.4% and includes both domestic andforeign assets. The tax went into effect from 2020 onwards<ref>{{Cite web |title=Bolivia - Individual - Other taxes |url=https://taxsummaries.pwc.com/bolivia/individual/other-taxes |access-date=2024-04-22 |website=taxsummaries.pwc.com |language=en-gb}}</ref>


==== Colombia ====
==== Colombia ====
Line 207: Line 210:
==== Germany ====
==== Germany ====
In order to bridge the [[wealth gap]] between rich and poor in Germany, the [[Social Democratic Party of Germany]] called for a nationwide wealth tax to be reintroduced in 2019.<ref>{{Cite web|last=Welle (www.dw.com)|first=Deutsche|title=Can a wealth tax bridge Germany's divide between rich and poor? {{!}} DW {{!}} 27.08.2019|url=https://www.dw.com/en/can-a-wealth-tax-bridge-germanys-divide-between-rich-and-poor/a-50185609|access-date=2021-04-22|website=DW.COM|language=en-GB}}</ref> According to the proposed tax reform, wealthy households would be required to pay an extra tax between 1% and 1.5%. A single household would need to pay 1% of their net worth on every euro surpassing €2 Million and married couple would have to pay for every euro surpassing €4 Million. A married household with a combined net worth of €4.2 Million would have to pay an annual wealth tax of €2,000.<ref>{{Cite web|last=Zeitung|first=Süddeutsche|title=SPD will Vermögensteuer wieder einführen|url=https://www.sueddeutsche.de/politik/vermoegensteuer-spd-schuldenbremse-1.4714505|access-date=2021-04-22|website=Süddeutsche.de|date=December 8, 2019 |language=de}}</ref> The proposition was eventually vetoed by the [[CDU/CSU]] and therefore never again considered.<ref>{{Cite web|title=ZEIT ONLINE {{!}} Lesen Sie zeit.de mit Werbung oder im PUR-Abo. Sie haben die Wahl.|url=https://www.zeit.de/zustimmung?url=https://www.zeit.de/politik/deutschland/2019-08/spd-olaf-scholz-vermoegenssteuer-finanzminister-geldpolitik?utm_referrer=https://de.wikipedia.org/|access-date=2021-04-22|website=www.zeit.de}}</ref>
In order to bridge the [[wealth gap]] between rich and poor in Germany, the [[Social Democratic Party of Germany]] called for a nationwide wealth tax to be reintroduced in 2019.<ref>{{Cite web|last=Welle (www.dw.com)|first=Deutsche|title=Can a wealth tax bridge Germany's divide between rich and poor? {{!}} DW {{!}} 27.08.2019|url=https://www.dw.com/en/can-a-wealth-tax-bridge-germanys-divide-between-rich-and-poor/a-50185609|access-date=2021-04-22|website=DW.COM|language=en-GB}}</ref> According to the proposed tax reform, wealthy households would be required to pay an extra tax between 1% and 1.5%. A single household would need to pay 1% of their net worth on every euro surpassing €2 Million and married couple would have to pay for every euro surpassing €4 Million. A married household with a combined net worth of €4.2 Million would have to pay an annual wealth tax of €2,000.<ref>{{Cite web|last=Zeitung|first=Süddeutsche|title=SPD will Vermögensteuer wieder einführen|url=https://www.sueddeutsche.de/politik/vermoegensteuer-spd-schuldenbremse-1.4714505|access-date=2021-04-22|website=Süddeutsche.de|date=December 8, 2019 |language=de}}</ref> The proposition was eventually vetoed by the [[CDU/CSU]] and therefore never again considered.<ref>{{Cite web|title=ZEIT ONLINE {{!}} Lesen Sie zeit.de mit Werbung oder im PUR-Abo. Sie haben die Wahl.|url=https://www.zeit.de/zustimmung?url=https://www.zeit.de/politik/deutschland/2019-08/spd-olaf-scholz-vermoegenssteuer-finanzminister-geldpolitik?utm_referrer=https://de.wikipedia.org/|access-date=2021-04-22|website=www.zeit.de}}</ref>

==== United Kingdom ====
In the aftermath of the [[COVID-19 pandemic]], 30 UK millionaires called on the then Chancellor of the Exechequer [[Rishi Sunak]] to introduce a wealth tax to: "Help pay for the recovery from the coronavirus crisis and tackle the yawning inequality gap". They argued that the UK tax system affords an unfair burden on working people while letting wealthy people off the hook<ref>{{Cite news |last=Neate |first=Rupert |last2=correspondent |first2=Rupert Neate Wealth |date=2021-10-24 |title=Millionaires petition Rishi Sunak to introduce wealth tax |url=https://www.theguardian.com/news/2021/oct/25/millionaires-petition-rishi-sunak-to-introduce-wealth-tax |access-date=2024-04-22 |work=The Guardian |language=en-GB |issn=0261-3077}}</ref>.


==Concentration of wealth==
==Concentration of wealth==
{{Main|Wealth concentration}}
{{Main|Wealth concentration}}
In 2014, French economist [[Thomas Piketty]] published a widely discussed<ref> [https://www.theguardian.com/money/2014/sep/21/-sp-thomas-piketty-bestseller-why "Why is Thomas Piketty's 700-page book a bestseller?"], ''The Guardian'', September 21 2014</ref> book entitled ''[[Capital in the Twenty-First Century]]'' that starts with the observation that economic inequality is increasing and proposes wealth taxes as a countermeasure. Piketty proposes a global system of progressive wealth taxes to help reduce inequality and avoid the trend towards a vast majority of wealth coming under the control of a tiny minority. This analysis was hailed as a major and important work by some economists.<ref>[https://www.washingtonpost.com/news/wonk/wp/2018/01/04/massive-new-data-set-suggests-inequality-is-about-to-get-even-worse/ "Massive new data set suggests inequality is about to get even worse"], ''The Washington Post'', January 4, 2018</ref><ref> [http://www.nybooks.com/articles/archives/2014/may/08/thomas-piketty-new-gilded-age/ "Why We're in a New Gilded Age"], ''The New York Review of Books'', May 8, 2014</ref><ref> [https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/52384/1/MPRA_paper_52384.pdf "The return of “patrimonial capitalism”: review of Thomas Piketty’s Capital in the 21st century"], ''Munich Personal RePEc Archive'', December 21, 2013</ref> Other economists have challenged Piketty's proposals and interpretations.<ref>"Piketty's theory about the increase in the return of capital in relation to labor is patently wrong, as anyone who has witnessed the rise of what is called the 'knowledge economy' (or anyone who has had investments in general) knows." [[Nassim Nicholas Taleb]], ''[[Skin in the Game (book)|Skin in the Game]]'' (2018), Random House</ref><ref>[http://reason.com/archives/2014/05/23/what-thomas-piketty-gets-wrong-about-cap "What Piketty Gets Wrong About Capitalism"], ''Reason'', May 23, 2014</ref><ref> [https://www.salon.com/2015/01/02/joseph_stiglitz_thomas_piketty_gets_income_inequality_wrong_partner/ "Joseph Stiglitz: Thomas Piketty gets income inequality wrong"], ''Salon'', January 5, 2015</ref>
In 2014, French economist [[Thomas Piketty]] published a widely discussed<ref> [https://www.theguardian.com/money/2014/sep/21/-sp-thomas-piketty-bestseller-why "Why is Thomas Piketty's 700-page book a bestseller?"], ''The Guardian'', September 21 2014</ref> book entitled ''[[Capital in the Twenty-First Century]]'' that starts with the observation that economic inequality is increasing and proposes wealth taxes as a countermeasure. Piketty proposes a global system of progressive wealth taxes to help reduce inequality and avoid the trend towards a vast majority of wealth coming under the control of a tiny minority. This analysis was hailed as a major and important work by some economists.<ref>[https://www.washingtonpost.com/news/wonk/wp/2018/01/04/massive-new-data-set-suggests-inequality-is-about-to-get-even-worse/ "Massive new data set suggests inequality is about to get even worse"], ''The Washington Post'', January 4, 2018</ref><ref> [http://www.nybooks.com/articles/archives/2014/may/08/thomas-piketty-new-gilded-age/ "Why We're in a New Gilded Age"], ''The New York Review of Books'', May 8, 2014</ref><ref> [https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/52384/1/MPRA_paper_52384.pdf "The return of “patrimonial capitalism”: review of Thomas Piketty’s Capital in the 21st century"], ''Munich Personal RePEc Archive'', December 21, 2013</ref> Other economists have challenged Piketty's proposals and interpretations.<ref>"Piketty's theory about the increase in the return of capital in relation to labor is patently wrong, as anyone who has witnessed the rise of what is called the 'knowledge economy' (or anyone who has had investments in general) knows." [[Nassim Nicholas Taleb]], ''[[Skin in the Game (book)|Skin in the Game]]'' (2018), Random House</ref><ref>[http://reason.com/archives/2014/05/23/what-thomas-piketty-gets-wrong-about-cap "What Piketty Gets Wrong About Capitalism"], ''Reason'', May 23, 2014</ref><ref> [https://www.salon.com/2015/01/02/joseph_stiglitz_thomas_piketty_gets_income_inequality_wrong_partner/ "Joseph Stiglitz: Thomas Piketty gets income inequality wrong"], ''Salon'', January 5, 2015</ref>

Moreover, there is much research to suggest that excessive economic inequality has negative effects on both economic growth and social cohesion<ref>{{Cite news |last=Hasanov |first=Fuad |last2=Izraeli |first2=Oded |date=2012-01-01 |title=How Much Inequality Is Necessary for Growth? |url=https://hbr.org/2012/01/how-much-inequality-is-necessary-for-growth |access-date=2024-04-22 |work=Harvard Business Review |issn=0017-8012}}</ref>. Spefically, the IMF have found that a gini-coefficient above 27 percent has negative effects on economic growth<ref>{{Cite web |date=2017-05-11 |title=A New Twist in the Link Between Inequality and Economic Development |url=https://www.imf.org/en/Blogs/Articles/2017/05/11/a-new-twist-in-the-link-between-inequality-and-economic-development |access-date=2024-04-22 |website=IMF |language=en}}</ref>. From an economic theoretical perspective, an excessively unequal concenctation of wealth might not lead to an efficient outcome since the resources are not spent on the development of human capital for people lower in the wealth distribution. A wealth tax could theoretically offset this problem by raising money to be spent on areas such as health and education, thus increasing human capital and productivity, thereby raising output.

There is additionally a theoretical argument to be made that due to the [[Marginal Utility|law of diminishing marginal utility]], the redistribution of wealth caused by such a tax could yeild a higher level of welfare for the population as a whole. This is due to the logic, that the welfare lost by a billionaire would be offset by the welfare gained by less wealthy people who would benefit more from the same amount of money.


=== France ===
=== France ===
Line 296: Line 306:


Saez and Zucman are two economists that worked on the "Ultra-Millionaire Tax" proposed by Senator [[Elizabeth Warren]]. In their paper, "Progressive Wealth Taxation," they assert that a potential wealth tax in the United States needs necessary parameters to limit detrimental effects on investment.<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Saez |first1=Emmanuel |last2=Zucman |first2=Gabriel |title=Progressive Wealth Taxation |url=https://www.brookings.edu/wp-content/uploads/2019/09/Saez-Zucman_conference-draft.pdf}}</ref> One parameter is a high wealth threshold to limit direct taxation on small business and entrepreneurship. The academic literature on the effects of wealth taxation on investment incentives are inconclusive in the United States; Saez and Zucman assert there are three reasons wealth taxes in European countries are weak comparisons to the United States when analyzing potential effects on investment. First, they claim [[tax competition]] between European countries allows for individuals to avoid taxation by allocating assets to a different country. Reallocating assets to avoid taxation is more difficult in the United States because tax filings apply equally to United States citizens no matter the country of current residence.<ref>{{cite web |title=How to Pay Taxes When You are Overseas |url=https://www.investopedia.com/financial-edge/0412/how-to-pay-taxes-if-youre-overseas.aspx |website=Investopedia}}</ref> Second, low exemption thresholds caused liquidity problems for some individuals who were on the lower end of wealth taxation thresholds. Third, they contend European wealth taxes need modernization and improved methods for systematic information gathering.
Saez and Zucman are two economists that worked on the "Ultra-Millionaire Tax" proposed by Senator [[Elizabeth Warren]]. In their paper, "Progressive Wealth Taxation," they assert that a potential wealth tax in the United States needs necessary parameters to limit detrimental effects on investment.<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Saez |first1=Emmanuel |last2=Zucman |first2=Gabriel |title=Progressive Wealth Taxation |url=https://www.brookings.edu/wp-content/uploads/2019/09/Saez-Zucman_conference-draft.pdf}}</ref> One parameter is a high wealth threshold to limit direct taxation on small business and entrepreneurship. The academic literature on the effects of wealth taxation on investment incentives are inconclusive in the United States; Saez and Zucman assert there are three reasons wealth taxes in European countries are weak comparisons to the United States when analyzing potential effects on investment. First, they claim [[tax competition]] between European countries allows for individuals to avoid taxation by allocating assets to a different country. Reallocating assets to avoid taxation is more difficult in the United States because tax filings apply equally to United States citizens no matter the country of current residence.<ref>{{cite web |title=How to Pay Taxes When You are Overseas |url=https://www.investopedia.com/financial-edge/0412/how-to-pay-taxes-if-youre-overseas.aspx |website=Investopedia}}</ref> Second, low exemption thresholds caused liquidity problems for some individuals who were on the lower end of wealth taxation thresholds. Third, they contend European wealth taxes need modernization and improved methods for systematic information gathering.

Saez and Zucman have also argued that a wealth tax with a high threshold, would have the benefit of mainly targeting individuals who have a high degree of liquid assets, circumventing the liquidity problem of small and medium sized businesses and less wealthy individuals. Moreover, they argue that such a tax would not necessarily reduce innovation since innovation is mostly done by young people who haven't acquired a big fortune yet<ref>{{Cite web |title=Estimating the economic impact of a wealth tax |url=https://www.brookings.edu/articles/estimating-the-economic-impact-of-a-wealth-tax/ |access-date=2024-04-22 |website=Brookings |language=en-US}}</ref>. This must be seen in the context that most of the wealthiest people in the US are older than average. Additionally, they argue that large established businesses use some of their wealth to retain market power, reducing innovation and competition<ref>{{Cite web |title=Estimating the economic impact of a wealth tax |url=https://www.brookings.edu/articles/estimating-the-economic-impact-of-a-wealth-tax/ |access-date=2024-04-22 |website=Brookings |language=en-US}}</ref>. Therefore, a wealth tax with a high tax payable threshold could potentially increase innovation.


Further proponents for a wealth tax claim it could have positive effects on investment in the United States. Some extremely wealthy people use their assets in unproductive ways.<ref>{{cite web |title=Proponents of Wealth Taxation Must Consider its Effects on Innovation |url=https://taxfoundation.org/wealth-tax-economic-impact/ |website=Tax Foundation|date=November 12, 2019 }}</ref><ref>{{cite web | ssrn=3966130 |last1=Gaillard |first1=Alexandre |last2=Wangner |first2=Philipp |title=Wealth, Returns, and Taxation: A Tale of Two dependencies |date=2022 | url = https://ssrn.com/abstract=3966130}}</ref> For example, an entrepreneur could generate much higher returns (though could conversely lose much more capital operating on leverage) than a wealthy individual with a conservative investment such as United States Treasury Bonds.
Further proponents for a wealth tax claim it could have positive effects on investment in the United States. Some extremely wealthy people use their assets in unproductive ways.<ref>{{cite web |title=Proponents of Wealth Taxation Must Consider its Effects on Innovation |url=https://taxfoundation.org/wealth-tax-economic-impact/ |website=Tax Foundation|date=November 12, 2019 }}</ref><ref>{{cite web | ssrn=3966130 |last1=Gaillard |first1=Alexandre |last2=Wangner |first2=Philipp |title=Wealth, Returns, and Taxation: A Tale of Two dependencies |date=2022 | url = https://ssrn.com/abstract=3966130}}</ref> For example, an entrepreneur could generate much higher returns (though could conversely lose much more capital operating on leverage) than a wealthy individual with a conservative investment such as United States Treasury Bonds.

Revision as of 13:01, 22 April 2024

A wealth tax (also called a capital tax or equity tax) is a tax on an entity's holdings of assets or an entity's net worth. This includes the total value of personal assets, including cash, bank deposits, real estate, assets in insurance and pension plans, ownership of unincorporated businesses, financial securities, and personal trusts (a one-off levy on wealth is a capital levy).[1] Typically, wealth taxation often involves the exclusion of an individual's liabilities, such as mortgages and other debts, from their total assets. Accordingly, this type of taxation is frequently denoted as a net wealth tax.

As of 2017, five of the 36 OECD countries had a personal wealth tax (down from 12 in 1990).[2]

Proponents often argue that wealth taxes can reduce income inequality by making it harder for individuals to accumulate large amounts of wealth.[1] Many critics of wealth taxes claim that wealth taxes can cause wealthy people and businesses to move their wealth to lower tax jurisdiction (such as tax havens).[3]

OECD countries with a wealth tax

The Global Revenue Statistics Database presents a roster of countries that have documented instances of revenue collected from wealth taxes (the data is limited to 1965-2021). A total of eight countries (Austria, Denmark, Finland, Germany, Netherlands, Norway, Sweden and Switzerland) were known to have collected revenue through a wealth tax in 1965. In the ensuing decades, the number of countries reporting wealth tax revenue increased gradually and reached its peak in 1995, with 12 countries (Austria, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Iceland, Italy, Netherlands, Norway, Spain, Sweden and Switzerland) reporting revenue generated from this form of taxation.

Although, as of 2021, only five of the 36 OECD countries continue to implement the wealth tax on individuals.

The five countries are Colombia, France, Norway, Spain and Switzerland.[4]

In practice

There are jurisdictions of sovereign nation states that require declaration of the taxpayer's balance sheet (assets and liabilities), and from that ask for a tax on net worth (assets minus liabilities), as a percentage of the net worth, or a percentage of the net worth exceeding a certain level. Wealth taxes can be limited to natural persons or they can be extended to also cover legal persons such as corporations.[5] In 1990, about a dozen European countries had a wealth tax, but by 2019, all but three had eliminated the tax because of the difficulties and costs associated with both design and enforcement.[6][7] Belgium, Norway, Spain, and Switzerland are the countries that raised revenue from net wealth taxes on individuals in 2019 with net wealth taxes accounting for 1.1% of overall tax revenues in Norway, 0.55% in Spain, and 3.6% in Switzerland for 2017.[7]

According to an OECD study on wealth taxes, it is "difficult to firmly argue that wealth taxes would have negative effects on entrepreneurship. The magnitude of the effects of wealth taxes on entrepreneurship is also unclear".[8]

A 2022 study found that wealth taxes are most likely to be implemented in the aftermath of major economic recessions.[9]

Example countries

Argentina

The official term used to denote the wealth tax in Argentina is "Impuesto sobre los Bienes Personales".

On 31 December 2021, Argentina’s tax authorities published General Resolution 912/2021, which introduces new modifications to the country’s wealth tax.[10]

The modifications made to the wealth tax in Argentina entail an augmentation of the non-taxable minimum to ARS 6,000,000. Moreover, residential real estate assets, wherein the owner's daily domicile is situated, shall not be subject to taxation if their worth equals or falls under ARS 30,000,000 (approx. US$138,000 at April 2023 official exchange rate) . Additionally, the taxation rate structure has been revised. Assets surpassing ARS 100,000,000 (approx. US$460,000 at April 2023 official exchange rate) will now be taxed at a rate of 1.50%, while those exceeding ARS 300,000,000 will be taxed at a rate of 1.75%.[10]

Tax rates for assets held in Argentina
Total assets (ARS) Tax on (1) (ARS) Tax on excess (%)
Over (1) Up to (inclusive)
0 3,000,000 - 0.50
3,000,000 6,500,000 15,000 0.75
6,500,000 18,000,000 41,250 1.00
18,000,000 100,000,000 156,250 1.25
100,000,000 300,000,000 1,181,250 1.50
300,000,000 and over 4,181,250 1.75
Tax rates for assets held abroad (for tax residents)
Value of assets held in Argentina and abroad (ARS) Tax rate (%)
Over Up to (inclusive)
0 3,000,000 0.70
3,000,000 6,500,000 1.20
6,500,000 18,000,000 1.80
18,000,000 and over 2.25

Before FY2021, for assets held within Argentina, the tax is progressive from 0.50% on assets above ARS 3,000,000 (approx. US$32,000 at April 2021 official exchange rate) to 1.25% on assets above ARS 18,000,000 (approx. US$193,000 at April 2021 official exchange rate).[11] For assets held outside of Argentina, the tax is progressive from 0.70% on assets above ARS 3,000,000 to 2.25% on assets above ARS 18,000,000.[12]

Belgium

The Act of 7 February 2018, which is effectively a "wealth tax", announced an annual tax on securities accounts that imposes a 0.15% annual tax on financial instruments kept in securities accounts that are worth more than €500,000 per account holder.[13]

The first taxable period started on 10 March 2018 and ended (at the latest on) 30 September 2018, for which the tax had to be paid by 30 Augusts 2019. The second taxable period runs from 1 October 2018 to 30 September 2019. In October 2019, the Belgian Constitutional Court issued a decision annulling this tax on securities accounts, with effect as of 1 October 2019.[14]

However, Belgium now re-introduced the annual tax on securities accounts law with some modifications in February 2021. The Belgian Parliament adopted the adjusted tax on securities accounts law applicable from 26 February 2021, with the first reference period ending on 30 September 2021. A solidarity tax of 0.15% is now applicable on securities accounts that reach or exceed €1,000,000 without regard to the number of accountholders, and the tax amount is limited to 10% of the difference between the taxable base and the threshold of €1,000,000.[15]

Bolivia

In December 2020, the Bolivian socialist government of President Luis Arce approved a wealth tax on resident and non-resident individuals with a net fortune of over 30 million Bolivian Boliviano. The tax is progressive with tax rates in the range of 1.4% to 2.4% and includes both domestic andforeign assets. The tax went into effect from 2020 onwards[16]

Colombia

On 1 January 2019, the Senate passed a tax reform bill that includes a lower corporate tax rate, a new tax rate for financial corporations, and a new wealth tax. For the years 2019, 2020, and 2021, the new wealth (equity) tax has been set at 1% for Colombian-resident individuals' worldwide net worth, and 1% for non-resident individuals on Colombian properties only, such as real estate, yachts, artwork, vessels, ships, and other assets with a net equity of at least COP5 billion (US$1.5 million). Shares in Colombian firms, accounts receivable from Colombian debtors, some portfolio assets, and financial lease agreements are all exempt from the tax.[17] Following the COVID-19 pandemic, the richest Colombians will face higher taxes on wages, dividends, and properties, as well as a one-time "solidarity levy" on high incomes. All of which is part of a new bill that was sent to congress in April 2021. The bill aims to collect about 25 trillion pesos (US$6.9 billion) a year through new taxes and budget restraints, equating to 2.2 percent of GDP.[18]

On 13 December 2022, the Colombian President Gustavo Petro enacted Law 2277 of 2022, which contains the tax reform proposals previously approved by congress. A new wealth tax will be introduced as a permanent tax on individuals with net worth as of 1 January of the relevant tax year exceeding 72,000 UVT. This amount will be calculated as the aggregate value of assets owned (real estate, investments, vehicles, financial products, accounts with financial institutions, etc.,), less the liabilities and debts. The tax will apply to the worldwide assets of resident individuals; nonresident individuals will be subject to wealth tax only on their Colombian assets. The tax rate is between 0 and 1,5% until 2026 and will be between 0 and 1% FY 2027 onwards.[19]

Wealth progressive tax rates applicable for 2023, 2024, 2025, and 2026
Brackets in UVT Progressive tax rate (%) Tax
From To
> 0 72,000 0.0 0
> 72,000 122,000 0.5 (Taxable wealth in UVT less than 72,000) x 0.5%
> 122,000 239,000 1.0 (Taxable wealth in UVT less than 122,000) x 1.0% 250 UVT
> 239,000 upwards 1.5 (Taxable wealth in UVT less than 239,000) x 1.5% 1,420 UVT
Wealth progressive tax rates applicable from 2027
Brackets in UVT Progressive tax rate (%) Tax
From To
> 0 72,000 0.0 0
> 72,000 122,000 0.5 (Taxable wealth in UVT less than 72,000) x 0.5%
> 122,000 239,000 1.0 (Taxable wealth in UVT less than 122,000) x 1.0% 250 UVT

France

Since 2018, France has a had a wealth tax based on real estate (impôt sur la fortune immobilière [fr], IFI). It is payable by individuals who own real estate assets with a combined value of more than €1,300,000. French residents with global assets and non-residents who own French real estate may be liable for IFI. For French residents, the figure is calculated on all global real estate assets, and for non-residents, the figure is calculated based on the total value of French property and real estate assets only.[20]

From 1989 to 2017, France had the solidarity tax on wealth (impôt de solidarité sur la fortune, ISF), an annual progressive wealth tax on any net assets above €800,000 for those with total net worth of €1,300,000 or more. Marginal rates ranged from 0.5% to 1.5%. In 2007, it collected €4.07 billion, accounting for 1.4% of total revenue.[21][22]

Italy

Two types of wealth taxes are imposed in Italy.

  • "Imposta sul valore degli immobile situati all’estero" or "IVIE", is a 0.76% tax imposed on real assets held outside Italy. The values of such assets are determined by the purchase price or current market value. Property taxes paid in the country where the real estate exists can offset IVIE. For real estate owned in a European Union (EU) member state and in a country which is a member of the European Economic Area (EEA) that has an exchange of information agreement with Italy, the wealth tax is based on the cadastral value in force in the foreign country. In instances where there is a lack of cadastral value, the wealth tax is based on the purchase cost of the property resulting or the market value in force where the real estate is located. No IVIE is due if the tax is lower than EUR 200; otherwise, the entire IVIE amount is due. If the real estate properties are subject to a property tax in the country in which they are located, the individual can deduct the amount paid from the tax due in the Italian tax return.[23]
  • Another tax, "Imposta sul valore delle Attivita` Finanziarie detenute all` Estero" or "IVAFE", is 0.20% and is levied on all financial assets located outside the country, including, so far as the language seems to imply, individual pension schemes such as 401(k)s and IRAs in the US.[24]

Netherlands

There is a tax called vermogensrendementheffing. Although its name (wealth yield tax) suggests that it is a tax on the yield of wealth, it qualifies as a wealth tax, since the actual yield (whether positive or negative) is not taken into account in its calculation. Up to and including 2016, the rate was fixed at 1.2% (30% taxation over an assumed yield of 4%). From the fiscal year of 2017 onwards, the tax rate progresses with wealth. See Income tax in the Netherlands. In addition to the vermogensrendementheffing, owners of real estate pay a tax called onroerendezaakbelasting, which is based on the estimated value of the real estate they own. This is a local tax, levied by the city council where the property is located.

Norway

0.7% (municipal) and 0.15% (national) a total of 0.85% levied on net assets exceeding 1,500,000 kr (approx. US$170,000) as of 2019.[25] For tax purposes, the value of the primary residence is valued to 25% of the market value, secondary residences to 90% of the market value, while working capital such as commercial real estate, stocks, and stock funds are valued at various percentages.[26] The Conservative Party, Progress Party and the Liberal Party have stated that they aim to reduce and eventually eliminate the wealth tax.[27]

Spain

There is a tax called Patrimonio. The tax rate is progressive, from 0.2 to 3.75% of net assets above the threshold of €700,000 after €300,000 primary residence allowance.[28] The exact amount varies between regions.

Switzerland

A progressive wealth tax that varies by residence location. Most cantons have no wealth tax for individual net worth less than SFr 100000 (approx. US$100,000) and progressively raise the tax rate on net assets with a top rate ranging from 0.13% to 0.94% depending on canton and municipality of residence.[29] Wealth tax is levied against worldwide assets of Swiss residents, but it is not levied against assets in Switzerland held by non-residents.[29][30]

Swiss wealth tax is regulated on a cantonal basis. All cantons levy a net wealth tax based on the balance of the worldwide gross assets minus debts, and tax rates can vary depending on the taxpayer's residency, with maximum rates varying from around 0.13% to 1.1%.[31]

Historical examples

Ancient Athens had a wealth tax called eisphora (see symmoria), and a wealth registry consisting of self-assessments (τίμημα), limited to the wealthiest. The registry was not very accurate.[32]: p.159 

The religion of Islam has a concept sometimes described as a wealth tax called Zakat.[33][34]

Iceland had a wealth tax until 2006 and a temporary wealth tax reintroduced in 2010 for four years. The tax was levied at a rate of 1.5% on net assets exceeding 75,000,000 kr for individuals and 100,000,000 kr for married couples.[citation needed]

Similar to Iceland, Denmark taxed household income above a certain exemption threshold, which was about the 98th percentile of the wealth distribution, until 1997. A dozen OECD countries imposed similar taxes until the 1990s, but the Danish wealth tax was the highest of its kind. Until the late 1980s, the marginal tax rate on wealth was 2.2 percent, leading to a very high rate on the return on wealth. After minimizing the tax for some years, the Danish government eventually abolished the tax altogether in 1997.[35]

Some other European countries have discontinued this kind of tax in recent years: Germany (1997), Finland (2006), Luxembourg (2006) and Sweden (2007).[36]

In the United Kingdom and other countries, property (real estate) is often a person's main asset, and has been taxed – for example, the window tax of 1696, the rates, to some extent the Council Tax.

Proposed examples

Germany

In order to bridge the wealth gap between rich and poor in Germany, the Social Democratic Party of Germany called for a nationwide wealth tax to be reintroduced in 2019.[37] According to the proposed tax reform, wealthy households would be required to pay an extra tax between 1% and 1.5%. A single household would need to pay 1% of their net worth on every euro surpassing €2 Million and married couple would have to pay for every euro surpassing €4 Million. A married household with a combined net worth of €4.2 Million would have to pay an annual wealth tax of €2,000.[38] The proposition was eventually vetoed by the CDU/CSU and therefore never again considered.[39]

United Kingdom

In the aftermath of the COVID-19 pandemic, 30 UK millionaires called on the then Chancellor of the Exechequer Rishi Sunak to introduce a wealth tax to: "Help pay for the recovery from the coronavirus crisis and tackle the yawning inequality gap". They argued that the UK tax system affords an unfair burden on working people while letting wealthy people off the hook[40].

Concentration of wealth

In 2014, French economist Thomas Piketty published a widely discussed[41] book entitled Capital in the Twenty-First Century that starts with the observation that economic inequality is increasing and proposes wealth taxes as a countermeasure. Piketty proposes a global system of progressive wealth taxes to help reduce inequality and avoid the trend towards a vast majority of wealth coming under the control of a tiny minority. This analysis was hailed as a major and important work by some economists.[42][43][44] Other economists have challenged Piketty's proposals and interpretations.[45][46][47]

Moreover, there is much research to suggest that excessive economic inequality has negative effects on both economic growth and social cohesion[48]. Spefically, the IMF have found that a gini-coefficient above 27 percent has negative effects on economic growth[49]. From an economic theoretical perspective, an excessively unequal concenctation of wealth might not lead to an efficient outcome since the resources are not spent on the development of human capital for people lower in the wealth distribution. A wealth tax could theoretically offset this problem by raising money to be spent on areas such as health and education, thus increasing human capital and productivity, thereby raising output.

There is additionally a theoretical argument to be made that due to the law of diminishing marginal utility, the redistribution of wealth caused by such a tax could yeild a higher level of welfare for the population as a whole. This is due to the logic, that the welfare lost by a billionaire would be offset by the welfare gained by less wealthy people who would benefit more from the same amount of money.

France

In 2017, when introducing the fiscal reform of the solidarity wealth tax, the government of the French president Emmanuel Macron used the first argument of capital flight. The other argument stated by the comity of evaluation of reforms on wealth fiscalism was that the previous wealth tax was not enough progressive for the top 0.1% wealthier. The “IFI” as the “ISF” are wealth tax thus they concerned high earners. A big part of people paying this tax are in the ninth decile of income distribution and the “IFI” represents one over two household in the wealthiest 0.01%. Therefore, in the general tax system, the “IFI” contributes, as did the ISF, to make the tax system more progressive. But this progressivity has limits: “the IFI represents on average 0.1% of income around the ninth decile and 1.2% of income of 0.1% of very well-off households in 2018. While the income tax rate under the ISF was stable overall, within the top 0.1% of income, the income tax rate under of the IFI declines for the wealthiest and falls to 0.6% for the top 0.01%.”[50] Broadly, this reform largely benefits to the 0.1% wealthier and did not make this wealth tax more progressive as it was supposed to be. In fact, it reduced the number of accountable people of wealth tax leaving the country but in term of investment, the gains of this reforms has been traduced in an increasing of dividend on capital earnings (37.4 billion from non-financial society had been paid) and not on direct investment on corporate (see “Capital flight”). In average and from different studies, those fiscal reforms benefited more to top-wealthier households. For Ben Jelloul and al. (2019), the reforms benefit for the top 1% more wealthier household with 5.5 point of disposable revenue. For Madec and al. (2019) it had affected on the top 2% of the wealthier households and for Pasquier and Sicsic (2019), the 5% of the top distribution perceived 57% of the gain of the fiscal reform.[51]

Revenue

Revenue from a wealth tax scheme depends largely on the presence of net wealth and wealth inequality within the target country. Revenue depends on the plan that is in place, but it generally can be modeled as , where t represents the tax rate and w is the amount of wealth affected by that tax rate.[52] Many plans include tax brackets, where a certain portion of the individual's wealth will be taxed at a given rate and any wealth beyond that amount will be taxed at a different rate.

A small number of countries have been using wealth tax regimes for some time. Revenues earned from wealth tax schemes vary by country from 0.98% of GDP in Switzerland to 0.22% in France, for example.[53] 2020 United States presidential candidate Elizabeth Warren claimed a wealth tax plan could generate 1.4% of GDP in revenue for the United States.[54]

According to data from the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD), the revenues generated from wealth taxes account for about 0.46% of all tax revenue on average in 2018 for countries which have wealth tax schemes in place. However this varies from country to country, the highest would be that of Luxembourg where it accounted for 7.18% of total tax revenue in 2018, the lowest would be Germany where it accounted for 0.03% of total tax revenue in 2018.

Wealth Tax Revenues by Country (US dollars, Billions) in 2018[53]
Country Recurrent Tax on Net Wealth Total Tax Revenue Wealth Tax over Total Tax Revenue
Luxembourg 1.995 27.8 7.18%
Switzerland 9.396 197.1 4.77%
Norway 2.470 169.6 1.46%
Spain 2.618 490.5 0.53%
Belgium 1.123 238.4 0.47%
Hungary 0.154 56.9 0.27%
France 2.166 1280.1 0.17%
Canada 0.335 564.8 0.06%
Germany 0.471 1526 0.03%

Estimates for a wealth tax's potential revenue in the United States vary. Several Democratic presidential candidates in the 2020 election have proposed wealth tax plans. Elizabeth Warren, for example, has proposed a wealth tax of 2% on net wealth above $50 million and 6% above $1 billion.[55] The conservative-leaning nonprofit Tax Foundation estimates revenue generated by Senator Warren's proposal would total around $2.6 trillion over the next 10 years.[56] Separate estimates from campaign advisors and economists Emmanuel Saez and Gabriel Zucman put the revenue at about 1% of GDP per year, in alignment with USD revenue estimates.[54][52] These estimates put Senator Warren's tax plan revenues at about $200 billion in 2020.[56] The sum of United States tax revenues in 2018 were $5 trillion in 2018,[53] meaning the tax collected by this plan would be equal to 4% of current tax revenues. Additionally, the Tax Foundation estimates 2020 presidential candidate Senator Bernie Sanders' wealth tax plan[57] would collect $3.2 trillion between 2020 and 2029.[56]

Previous proposals for a wealth tax in the United States had already existed. Eileen Myles proposed a net assets tax in her presidential campaign in 1992,[58] as did Donald Trump during his presidential campaign in 2000.[59]

A net wealth tax may also be designed to be revenue-neutral if it is used to broaden the tax base, stabilize the economy, and reduce individual income and other taxes.

Effect on investment

A wealth tax serves as a negative reinforcer ("use it or lose it"), which incentivizes the productive use of assets (rather than letting assets accumulate without being used). According to University of Pennsylvania Law School professors David Shakow and Reed Shuldiner, "a wealth tax also taxes capital that is not productively employed. Thus, a wealth tax can be viewed as a tax on potential income from capital."[60] Net wealth taxes can complement rather than replace gift taxes, capital gains taxes, and inheritance taxes to increase administrability and the effectiveness of enforcement efforts.

In their article, "Investment Effects of Wealth Taxes Under Uncertainty and Irreversibility," Rainer Niemann and Caren Sureth-Sloane found that the effects of wealth taxation on investment mainly depends upon the tax method employed and the broadness of the wealth threshold for taxation.[61] Niemann and Sureth-Sloane found that, "Broadening the wealth tax base tends to accelerate investment during high interest rate periods." Caren Sureth and Ralf Maiterth concluded that wealth tax revenues from entrepreneurs may decrease in the long term and the revenue from a wealth tax may be negative if the wealth taxation thresholds are too low.[62]

Saez and Zucman are two economists that worked on the "Ultra-Millionaire Tax" proposed by Senator Elizabeth Warren. In their paper, "Progressive Wealth Taxation," they assert that a potential wealth tax in the United States needs necessary parameters to limit detrimental effects on investment.[63] One parameter is a high wealth threshold to limit direct taxation on small business and entrepreneurship. The academic literature on the effects of wealth taxation on investment incentives are inconclusive in the United States; Saez and Zucman assert there are three reasons wealth taxes in European countries are weak comparisons to the United States when analyzing potential effects on investment. First, they claim tax competition between European countries allows for individuals to avoid taxation by allocating assets to a different country. Reallocating assets to avoid taxation is more difficult in the United States because tax filings apply equally to United States citizens no matter the country of current residence.[64] Second, low exemption thresholds caused liquidity problems for some individuals who were on the lower end of wealth taxation thresholds. Third, they contend European wealth taxes need modernization and improved methods for systematic information gathering.

Saez and Zucman have also argued that a wealth tax with a high threshold, would have the benefit of mainly targeting individuals who have a high degree of liquid assets, circumventing the liquidity problem of small and medium sized businesses and less wealthy individuals. Moreover, they argue that such a tax would not necessarily reduce innovation since innovation is mostly done by young people who haven't acquired a big fortune yet[65]. This must be seen in the context that most of the wealthiest people in the US are older than average. Additionally, they argue that large established businesses use some of their wealth to retain market power, reducing innovation and competition[66]. Therefore, a wealth tax with a high tax payable threshold could potentially increase innovation.

Further proponents for a wealth tax claim it could have positive effects on investment in the United States. Some extremely wealthy people use their assets in unproductive ways.[67][68] For example, an entrepreneur could generate much higher returns (though could conversely lose much more capital operating on leverage) than a wealthy individual with a conservative investment such as United States Treasury Bonds.

A wealth tax could lead to negative effects on investment, saving, and economic growth. In the article, "Economic effects of wealth taxation," Kyle Pomerleau states, "A wealth tax, even levied at an apparently low annual rate, places a significant burden on saving."[69] The degree of this impact on savings and investments is reliant on the openness of the United States economy. A wealth tax would shrink national saving and increase foreign ownership of assets. The potential decrease in national savings leads to a decrease in capital stock. An estimate from the Penn Wharton Budget Model indicates that if the revenue from the wealth tax proposed by Elizabeth Warren were used to finance non-productive government spending, GDP would decrease by 2.1 percent by 2050, capital stock would decrease by 6.5 percent, and wages would decrease by 2.3 percent.[70] Some opponents also point out that redistribution through a wealth tax is an inherently counterintuitive way to foster economic growth. Richard Epstein, a senior fellow at the Hoover Institution, contents, "The classical liberal approach wants to simplify taxation and reduce regulation to spur growth. Plain old growth is a much better social tonic that the toxic Warren Wealth Tax."[71]

Criticisms

There are many arguments against the implementation of a wealth tax, including claims that a wealth tax would be unconstitutional (in the United States), that property would be too hard to value, and that wealth taxes would reduce the rate of innovation.

Capital flight

A 2006 article in The Washington Post titled "Old Money, New Money Flee France and Its Wealth Tax" pointed out some of the harm caused by France's wealth tax. The article gave examples of how the tax caused capital flight, brain drain, loss of jobs, and, ultimately, a net loss in tax revenue. Among other things, the article stated, "Éric Pichet, author of a French tax guide, estimates the wealth tax earns the government about $2.6 billion a year but has cost the country more than $125 billion in capital flight since 1998."[72][73]

In fact the wealth tax named "Impôt sur les Grandes Fortunes" (IGF) ["tax on great wealth"] had been created in 1980, then suppressed in 1986 before finally being reintroduced in 1988 under the name “Impôt de Solidarité sur la Fortune” (ISF) ["solidarity tax on wealth"]. In 1999 a new higher tax category was added which increased the money collected from 0.09% of GDP in 1990 to 0.16% in 2004.

For example, in 2003, 370 ISF’s accountables people left France and it continued to grow year by year except between 2010 and 2011 when the tax threshold has been raised and accountable people were discarded from it. This capital flight only decrease after 2015 and in 2017 when the French government announced that it will suppress this tax. After the reforms implementation, there were only 163 departures of wealth tax people in 2018.[74] The capital flight was one of the argument to reforms the wealth tax. After 2017, in the financial law of 2018, the new wealth tax was introduced with other tax reforms. The fiscal reform thus included a unique forfeit tax on saving, combined with the replacement of ISF by the IFI “Impôt sur la Fortune Immobilière” (IFI) which reduce the wealth tax to real-estate propriety only and finally a decrease of the corporate tax. This argument of capital flight takes its roots on an economic theory, the runoff theory. By decreasing the wealth tax, the wealth households are supposed to come back inside the country to invest and thus raised the GDP growth which will have effect on all the population by reducing unemployment and boost the economy. In France, the fiscal reform did not have the expected effects of runoff. In fact, the capital flight due to wealth tax household leaving only represented 0.3% and 0.5% of the total amount of money collected by the solidarity tax on wealth, between 2004 and 2015. On the other hand, this decrease of the wealth tax represented an income loss of 2.9 billion for the state.[75]

In term of investment, there were fewer investments in real-estate from people accountable of wealth tax. However, this movement could be explained more by the increase in household income, the low level of interest rates on mortgage loans and the general dynamics of the real estate market than by a sale, on the part of wealthy households, of property subject to the IFI for the benefit of investments in transferable securities, therefore the result in investment on corporate are not significant. Moreover, the fiscal reform on wealth tax had an insignificant level at the macroeconomic level for the corporate funds. For example, in 2020 for the non-financial society, the part of listed and non-listed share has been lower from the average of the previous period 2001-2019. It is also hard to measure the effect on corporate investment because of the Covid-19 crises which caused a shut-down of the economy in 2020.[76]

Valuation issues

In 2012, the Wall Street Journal wrote that: "the wealth tax has a fatal flaw: valuation. It has been estimated that 62% of the wealth of the top 1% is "non-financial" – i.e., vehicles, real estate, and (most importantly) private business. Private businesses account for nearly 40% of their wealth and are the largest single category." A particular issue for small business owners is that they cannot accurately value their private business until it is sold. Furthermore, business owners could easily make their businesses look much less valuable than they really are, through accounting, valuations and assumptions about the future. "Even the rich don't know exactly what they're worth in any given moment."[77]

Examples of such fraud and malfeasance were revealed in 2013, when French budget minister Jérôme Cahuzac was discovered shifting financial assets into Swiss bank accounts in order to avoid the wealth tax. After further investigation, a French finance ministry official said, "A number of government officials minimised their wealth, by negligence or with intent, but without exceeding 5–10 per cent of their real worth ... however, there are some who have deliberately tried to deceive the authorities."[78] Yet again, in October 2014, France's Finance chairman and President of the National Assembly, Gilles Carrez, was found to have avoided paying the French wealth tax (ISF) for three years by applying a 30 percent tax allowance on one of his homes. However, he had previously converted the home into an SCI, a private, limited company to be used for rental purposes. The 30 percent allowance does not apply to SCI holdings. Once this was revealed, Carrez declared, "if the tax authorities think that I should pay the wealth tax, I won't argue." Carrez is one of more than 60 French parliamentarians battling with the tax offices over 'dodgy' asset declarations.[79]

Moreover, this problem of wealth devaluation is undermined by the administration itself. For example, in France in 1999, the government introduced the notion of “the measured application of the tax law”.[80] But this application of the law is mostly reserved for the self-declared tax, like the wealth tax. It means that if there is a fraud in the declaration, there will be no sanction if the household concerned correct his mistake, even if it might have been done in purpose. This flexibility granted to self-declared taxes is indeed unequal. In fact the other tax that concerned most of the households, like income taxes, can’t be self-declared and this fraud flexibility benefits only to the richer household. More broadly, this self-declaration tax has developed what the sociologist Alexis Spire called “tax law domestication”, which enable richest part of the population to employed fiscal specialist to optimize their declaration and minimize the amount of the wealth tax. Once again those opportunity of optimization, as the flexibility in sanctions are unequally distributed in the tax spectrum and thus in the different part of the population.

Social effects

Opponents of wealth taxes have argued that there is "an undercurrent of envy in the campaign against extremes of wealth."[81] Two Yale University/London School of Economics studies (2006, 2008) on relative income yielded results asserting that 50 percent of the public would prefer to earn less money, as long as they earned as much or more than their neighbor.[82][83]

Many analysts and scholars[who?] assert that since wealth taxes are a form of direct asset collection, as well as double-taxation, they are antithetical to personal freedom and individual liberty. They further contend that free nations should have no business helping themselves arbitrarily to the personal belongings of any group of its citizens.[84] Further, these opponents may say wealth taxes place the authority of the government ahead of the rights of the individual, and ultimately undermine the concept of personal sovereignty. The Daily Telegraph editor Allister Heath critically described wealth taxes as Marxian in concept and ethically destructive to the values of democracies, "Taxing already acquired property drastically alters the relationship between citizen and state: we become leaseholders, rather than freeholders, with accumulated taxes over long periods of time eventually "returning" our wealth to the state. It breaches a key principle that has made this country great: the gradual expansion of property ownership and the democratisation of wealth."[85]

Past repeals

In 2004, a study by the Institut de l'enterprise investigated why several European countries were eliminating wealth taxes and made the following observations: 1. Wealth taxes contributed to capital drain, promoting the flight of capital as well as discouraging investors from coming in. 2. Wealth taxes had high management cost and relatively low returns. 3. Wealth taxes distorted resource allocation, particularly involving certain exemptions and unequal valuation of assets. In its summary, the institute found that the "wealth taxes were not as equitable as they appeared".[86]

In a 2011 study, the London School of Economics examined wealth taxes that were being considered by the Labour party in the United Kingdom between 1974 and 1976 but were ultimately abandoned. The findings of the study revealed that the British evaluated similar programs in other countries and determined that the Spanish wealth tax may have contributed to a banking crisis and the French wealth tax had been undergoing review by its government for being unpopular and overly complex. As efforts progressed, concerns were developing over the practicality and implementation of wealth taxes as well as worry that they would undermine confidence in the British economy. Eventually, plans were dropped. Former British Chancellor Denis Healey concluded that attempting to implement wealth taxes was a mistake, "We had committed ourselves to a Wealth Tax: but in five years I found it impossible to draft one which would yield enough revenue to be worth the administrative cost and political hassle." The conclusion of the study stated that there were lingering questions, such as the impacts on personal saving and small business investment, consequences of capital flight, complexity of implementation, and ability to raise predicted revenues that must be adequately addressed before further consideration of wealth taxes.[87]

United States

See also Pollock v. Farmers' Loan & Trust Co.; Sixteenth Amendment to the United States Constitution

In part because a wealth tax has never been implemented in the United States, there is no legal consensus about its constitutionality. As evidenced below, much scholarly debate on the topic hinges on whether or not such a tax is understood to be a "direct tax," per Article 1, Section 9 of the Constitution, which requires that the burden of "direct taxes" be apportioned across the states by their population.

Barry L. Isaacs interprets current case law in the United States to hold that a wealth tax is a direct tax under Article 1, Section 9.[88][89] Given the extreme difficulty of apportioning a wealth tax by state population, the implementation of a wealth tax in the United States would require either a constitutional amendment or the overturning of current case law.[90] Unlike federal wealth taxes, states and localities are not bound by Article 1, Section 9, which is why they are able to levy taxes on real estate.[91]

Other legal scholars have argued that a wealth tax does not represent a direct tax and that such a tax could be implemented in the United States without a constitutional amendment. In a lengthy essay from 2018, authors in the Indiana Journal of Law argued that "... the belief that the U.S. Constitution effectively makes a national wealth tax impossible ... is wrong."[92]: 112  The authors noted that in the 1796 Supreme Court decision for Hylton v. United States, Supreme Court justices who had personally taken part in the creation of the U.S. Constitution "unanimously rejected a challenge to the constitutionality of an annual tax on carriages, a tax akin to a national wealth tax in that it taxed a luxury property."[92]: 114  However, Alexander Hamilton, who supported the carriage tax, told the Supreme Court that it was constitutional because it was an "excise tax", not a direct tax. Hamilton's brief defines direct taxes as "Capitation or poll taxes, taxes on lands and buildings, general assessments, whether on the whole property of individuals or on their whole real or personal estate" which would include the wealth tax.[93] Tax scholars have repeatedly noted that the critical difference between income taxes and wealth taxes, the realization requirement, is a matter of administrative convenience, not a constitutional requirement.[citation needed]

To prevent capital flight, proponents of wealth taxes have argued for the implementation of a one-time exit tax on high net worth individuals who renounce their citizenship and leave the country.[94] An additional constitutional objection to such a tax could be raised on the grounds that it violates the takings clause of the Fifth Amendment, which prohibits the federal government from taking private property for public use without just compensation.[95]

In 2023, Texas voters approved a constitutional amendment prohibiting state lawmakers from imposing a wealth tax.[96][97][98]

Germany

The Federal Constitutional Court of Germany in Karlsruhe found that wealth taxes "would need to be confiscatory in order to bring about any real redistribution". In addition, the court held that the sum of wealth tax and income tax should not be greater than half of a taxpayer's income. "The tax thus gives rise to a dilemma: either it is ineffective in fighting inequalities, or it is confiscatory – and it is for that reason that the Germans chose to eliminate it." Thus, finding such wealth taxes unconstitutional in 1995.[99] In 2006, the Constitutional Court revised this decision on the so-called "Halbteilungsgrundsatz", stating that "From the property guarantee of the Basic Law, no generally binding absolute upper limit of taxation in the vicinity of a half division can be derived."[100]

See also

References

  1. ^ a b Edward N. Wolff, "Time for a Wealth Tax?", Boston Review, Feb–Mar 1996 (recommending a net wealth tax for the US of 0.05% for the first $100,000 in assets to 0.3% for assets over $1,000,000
  2. ^ "Global Revenue Statistics Database".
  3. ^ Pichet, Eric (June 17, 2011). "The Economic Consequences of the French Wealth Tax". SSRN 1268381.
  4. ^ "Global Revenue Statistics Database".
  5. ^ "Taxation of Wealth"
  6. ^ Andelman, David A. (February 17, 2019). "A wealth tax is a bad idea". www.cnn.com/. CNN. Retrieved December 3, 2021.
  7. ^ a b Zeballos-Roig, Joseph. "4 European countries still have a wealth tax. Here's how much success they've each had". Business Insider. Retrieved April 22, 2021.
  8. ^ "The Role and Design of Net Wealth Taxes in the OECD". OECD Tax Policy Studies. 26. OECD: 114.
  9. ^ Limberg, Julian; Seelkopf, Laura (2022). "The historical origins of wealth taxation". Journal of European Public Policy. 29 (5): 670–688. doi:10.1080/13501763.2021.1992486. ISSN 1350-1763. S2CID 245307172.
  10. ^ a b Nunez, Rodolfo P. Canese Mendez, Cecilia (January 12, 2022). "Argentina – Wealth Tax Changes to Non Taxable Minimum, Tax Rates - KPMG Global". KPMG. Retrieved April 19, 2023.{{cite web}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  11. ^ "Bienes Personales for Assets within Argentina". Administración Federal de Ingresos Públicos. April 27, 2021. Retrieved April 27, 2021.
  12. ^ "Bienes Personales for Assets outside of Argentina". Administración Federal de Ingresos Públicos. April 27, 2021. Retrieved April 27, 2021.
  13. ^ "What the Belgian 'Wealth Tax' means for you..." The Fry Group. June 21, 2018. Retrieved April 22, 2021.
  14. ^ "Belgium - Individual - Other taxes". taxsummaries.pwc.com. Retrieved April 20, 2023.
  15. ^ "Belgium re-introduces an annual tax on securities accounts". www.regnology.net. Retrieved April 20, 2023.
  16. ^ "Bolivia - Individual - Other taxes". taxsummaries.pwc.com. Retrieved April 22, 2024.
  17. ^ "Colombia's new tax bill comes into effect". www.internationalinvestment.net. January 31, 2019. Retrieved April 22, 2021.
  18. ^ "Colombia to Tax Rich After Pandemic Leaves Debt, Mass Hunger". Bloomberg.com. April 15, 2021. Retrieved April 22, 2021.
  19. ^ "Deloitte | tax@hand". www.taxathand.com. Retrieved April 20, 2023.
  20. ^ "Understanding French Wealth Tax: Are You Liable?". FrenchEntrée. April 5, 2022. Retrieved April 20, 2023.
  21. ^ French wealth tax explained in full in The Connexion
  22. ^ "Worldwide personal tax guide 2013–2014: France" (PDF). HSBC. July 1, 2013. Retrieved December 11, 2014.
  23. ^ "Italy - Individual - Other taxes". taxsummaries.pwc.com. Retrieved April 20, 2023.
  24. ^ [1], agenziaentrate.gov.it/
  25. ^ Skatteetaten. "Skatteetaten – Wealth tax". www.skatteetaten.no. Retrieved December 1, 2019.
  26. ^ Skatteetaten. "Skatteetaten - Taxes". www.skatteetaten.no. Retrieved September 14, 2021.
  27. ^ NTB (February 13, 2014). "Politisk flertall for å fjerne formuesskatten" (in Norwegian). Dagens Næringsliv. Retrieved March 19, 2014.
  28. ^ "Tramos en el Impuesto sobre el Patrimonio: tipo impositivo". Rankia. May 13, 2014.
  29. ^ a b Switzerland Wealth Tax, Lowtax.net
  30. ^ "Worldwide personal tax guide 2012 – 2013" (PDF). HSBC.
  31. ^ "Wealth Tax". Taxolution Advisory LLC. August 4, 2021. Retrieved April 20, 2023.
  32. ^ Christ, Matthew R. (1990). "Liturgy Avoidance and Antidosis in Classical Athens". Transactions of the American Philological Association. 120: 147–169. doi:10.2307/283983. JSTOR 283983.
  33. ^ Muḥammad ibn al-Ḥasan Ṭūsī (2010), Concise Description of Islamic Law and Legal Opinions, ISBN 978-1904063292, pp. 131–135.
  34. ^ Hefner R.W. (2006). "Islamic economics and global capitalism". Society. 44 (1): 16–22. doi:10.1007/bf02690463. S2CID 153432583. Zakat is a tax levied on income and wealth for the purpose of their purification.
  35. ^ Jakobsen, Katrine; Jakobsen, Kristian; Kleven, Henrik; Zucman, Gabriel (2019). "Wealth Taxation and Wealth Accumulation: Theory and Evidence From Denmark". The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 135 (1): 328–388. doi:10.1093/qje/qjz032. hdl:10419/258899.
  36. ^ "Sweden axes wealth tax". www.ft.com. Retrieved March 28, 2007.
  37. ^ Welle (www.dw.com), Deutsche. "Can a wealth tax bridge Germany's divide between rich and poor? | DW | 27.08.2019". DW.COM. Retrieved April 22, 2021.
  38. ^ Zeitung, Süddeutsche (December 8, 2019). "SPD will Vermögensteuer wieder einführen". Süddeutsche.de (in German). Retrieved April 22, 2021.
  39. ^ "ZEIT ONLINE | Lesen Sie zeit.de mit Werbung oder im PUR-Abo. Sie haben die Wahl". www.zeit.de. Retrieved April 22, 2021.
  40. ^ Neate, Rupert; correspondent, Rupert Neate Wealth (October 24, 2021). "Millionaires petition Rishi Sunak to introduce wealth tax". The Guardian. ISSN 0261-3077. Retrieved April 22, 2024. {{cite news}}: |last2= has generic name (help)
  41. ^ "Why is Thomas Piketty's 700-page book a bestseller?", The Guardian, September 21 2014
  42. ^ "Massive new data set suggests inequality is about to get even worse", The Washington Post, January 4, 2018
  43. ^ "Why We're in a New Gilded Age", The New York Review of Books, May 8, 2014
  44. ^ "The return of “patrimonial capitalism”: review of Thomas Piketty’s Capital in the 21st century", Munich Personal RePEc Archive, December 21, 2013
  45. ^ "Piketty's theory about the increase in the return of capital in relation to labor is patently wrong, as anyone who has witnessed the rise of what is called the 'knowledge economy' (or anyone who has had investments in general) knows." Nassim Nicholas Taleb, Skin in the Game (2018), Random House
  46. ^ "What Piketty Gets Wrong About Capitalism", Reason, May 23, 2014
  47. ^ "Joseph Stiglitz: Thomas Piketty gets income inequality wrong", Salon, January 5, 2015
  48. ^ Hasanov, Fuad; Izraeli, Oded (January 1, 2012). "How Much Inequality Is Necessary for Growth?". Harvard Business Review. ISSN 0017-8012. Retrieved April 22, 2024.
  49. ^ "A New Twist in the Link Between Inequality and Economic Development". IMF. May 11, 2017. Retrieved April 22, 2024.
  50. ^ DHERBECOURT Clément, LOPEZ FORERO Margarita, « Quelle taxation du capital, avant et après la réforme de 2018 ? », La note d'analyse, 2019/4 (n° 81), p. 1-11. DOI : 10.3917/lna.081.0001. URL : https://www.cairn.info/revue-la-note-d-analyse-2019-4-page-1.htm
  51. ^ COMITÉ D’ÉVALUATION DES RÉFORMES DE LA FISCALITÉ DU CAPITAL, "Premier rapport", 10/2019, p.209, URL: https://www.strategie.gouv.fr/sites/strategie.gouv.fr/files/atoms/files/fs-2019-fiscalite-capital-01-10-2019.pdf
  52. ^ a b Saez, Zucman (September 4, 2019). "Progressive Wealth Taxation" (PDF). Brookings.
  53. ^ a b c OECD (2020), "Revenue Statistics: Comparative tables", OECD Tax Statistics (database), doi:10.1787/data-00262-en (accessed on 17 February 2020).
  54. ^ a b Saez and Zucman. "Letter to Elizabeth Warren" (PDF).
  55. ^ "Ultra-Millionaire Tax". Elizabeth Warren.
  56. ^ a b c "A Wealth Tax Would Increase Foreign Ownership of U.S. Capital". Tax Foundation. January 27, 2020. Retrieved March 12, 2020.
  57. ^ "Tax on Extreme Wealth". Bernie Sanders.
  58. ^ Rothkopf, Joanna (January 20, 2016). "A Look Back at Eileen Myles' Revolutionary, 'Openly-Female' Write-In Presidential Campaign". Jezebel. Retrieved October 28, 2018.
  59. ^ "Trump proposes massive one-time tax on the rich – November 9, 1999". cnn.com. Retrieved January 8, 2017.
  60. ^ Shakow, David and Shuldiner, Reed, Symposium on Wealth Taxes Part II, New York University School of Law Tax Law Review, 53 Tax L. Rev. 499, 506 Summer, 2000
  61. ^ Niemann, Rainer (2015). "Investment Effects of Wealth Taxes Under Uncertainty and Irreversibility" (PDF). International Taxation Research Paper. WU International Taxation Research Paper Series. doi:10.2139/ssrn.2685104. S2CID 386291.
  62. ^ Sureth-Sloane, Caren (2005). "Wealth Tax as Alternative Minimum Tax". doi:10.2139/ssrn.700297. hdl:10419/27034. S2CID 28648794. {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  63. ^ Saez, Emmanuel; Zucman, Gabriel. "Progressive Wealth Taxation" (PDF). {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  64. ^ "How to Pay Taxes When You are Overseas". Investopedia.
  65. ^ "Estimating the economic impact of a wealth tax". Brookings. Retrieved April 22, 2024.
  66. ^ "Estimating the economic impact of a wealth tax". Brookings. Retrieved April 22, 2024.
  67. ^ "Proponents of Wealth Taxation Must Consider its Effects on Innovation". Tax Foundation. November 12, 2019.
  68. ^ Gaillard, Alexandre; Wangner, Philipp (2022). "Wealth, Returns, and Taxation: A Tale of Two dependencies". SSRN 3966130.
  69. ^ Pomerleau, Kyle. "Economic Effects of Wealth Taxation". AEI.
  70. ^ "Senator Elizabeth Warren's Wealth Tax: Budgetary and Economic Effects". Penn Wharton University of Pennsylvania Budget Model. December 12, 2019.
  71. ^ Epstein, Richard. "The Toxic Warren Wealth Tax". The Hoover Institution.
  72. ^ Washington Post. Old Money, New Money Flee France and Its Wealth Tax, July 16, 2006
  73. ^ Pichet, Eric (September 15, 2008). "The Economic Consequences of the French Wealth Tax". SSRN 1268381 – via papers.ssrn.com.
  74. ^ COMITÉ D’ÉVALUATION DES RÉFORMES DE LA FISCALITÉ DU CAPITAL, "Premier rapport", 01/10/2019 p.203-206, URL: https://www.strategie.gouv.fr/sites/strategie.gouv.fr/files/atoms/files/fs-2019-fiscalite-capital-01-10-2019.pdf
  75. ^ Vie publique, "Réformes de la fiscalité du capital : objectif atteint ?" 14/10/2020 https://www.vie-publique.fr/en-bref/276640-fiscalite-du-capital-et-attractivite-economique-objectif-atteint
  76. ^ Comité d’évaluation des réformes de la fiscalité du capital, "Deuxième rapport", 10/2020, URL: 276598.pdf (vie-publique.fr)
  77. ^ The Problem with a Wealth tax, Wall Street Journal January 11, 2012
  78. ^ Chazan, David (October 22, 2014). "French MPs face investigation over tax scandal". The Telegraph.
  79. ^ France Medias Monde. "France's Finance Chairman facing tax nightmare". RFI News (National French Radio).
  80. ^ SPIRE Alexis, « Fraude fiscale : une régulation à deux vitesses », Revue Projet, 2014/4 (N° 341), p. 23-30. DOI : 10.3917/pro.341.0023. URL : https://www.cairn.info/revue-projet-2014-4-page-23.htm
  81. ^ An Immodest Proposal: A Global Tax on the Super Rich, Businessweek, October 23, 2013
  82. ^ Does Envy Destroy Social Fundamentals? The Impact of Relative Income Position on Social Capital, 2006
  83. ^ Social Capital and Relative Income Concerns: Evidence from 26 Countries, 2008
  84. ^ Umfairteilung, Economist, September 8, 2012
  85. ^ "A wealth tax would be ethically wrong and economically destructive". www.telegraph.co.uk. February 19, 2013.
  86. ^ Wealth Tax in Europe: Why The Decline? Institut de l'enterprise, June 2004
  87. ^ Why was a wealth tax for the UK abandoned?: Lessons for the policy process and tackling wealth inequality, London School of Economics, 2011
  88. ^ Isaacs, Barry L. (1977–78) "Do We Want a Wealth Tax in America?" 32 U. Miami L. Rev. 23
  89. ^ See, for example, the United States Supreme Court case of Fernandez v. Wiener, in which the Court stated that a direct tax is a tax "which falls upon the owner merely because he is owner, regardless of his use or disposition of the property." Fernandez v. Wiener, 326 U.S. 340, 66 S. Ct. 178, 45–2 U.S. Tax Cas. (CCH) ¶10,239 (1945).
  90. ^ Jensen, Erik M. (2004) "Interpreting the Sixteenth Amendment (By Way of the Direct-Tax Clauses)" 21 Const. Comment. 355
  91. ^ Yglesias, Matthew (March 6, 2013). "America Does Tax Wealth, Just Not Very Intelligently". Slate. Retrieved March 18, 2013.
  92. ^ a b Johnsen, Dawn; Dellinger, Walter (January 1, 2018). "The Constitutionality of a National Wealth Tax". 93 Indiana Law Journal 111 (2018). 93 (1). ISSN 0019-6665.
  93. ^ Feldman, Noah (January 30, 2019). "Wealth Tax's Legality Depends on What 'Direct' Means". Bloomberg News.
  94. ^ Homan, Timothy R. (October 18, 2019). "Warren's surge brings new scrutiny to signature wealth tax". The Hill. Retrieved October 20, 2019.
  95. ^ Griffith, Joel (April 30, 2019). "Elizabeth Warren's 'Wealth Tax' Has Three Strikes Against It: Here's Why". Heritage Foundation.
  96. ^ "Texas Proposition 3 Election Results 2023: Prohibit Net Worth Tax". The New York Times. November 7, 2023. Retrieved March 2, 2024.
  97. ^ Freed, Benjamin; Autullo, Ryan (November 8, 2023). "Texas Votes to Outlaw Additional Taxes on Wealthy Residents". Bloomberg Industry Group News. Retrieved March 2, 2024.
  98. ^ Méndez, María; Schumacher, Yuriko (September 15, 2023). "Taxes, state parks, infrastructure: What you need to know about the Nov. 7 constitutional amendments election". The Texas Tribune. Retrieved March 2, 2024.
  99. ^ Economist. Umfairteilung, Economist, September 8, 2012
  100. ^ Der Spiegel. Staat darf über 50 Prozent Steuern kassieren, March 16, 2006

Further reading