The superhedging price is a coherent risk measure. The superhedging price of a portfolio (A) is equivalent to the smallest amount necessary to be paid for an admissible portfolio (B) at the current time so that at some specified future time the value of B is at least as great as A. In a complete market the superhedging price is equivalent to the price for hedging the initial portfolio.[1]

Mathematical definition

edit

If the set of equivalent martingale measures is denoted by EMM then the superhedging price of a portfolio X is   where   is defined by

 .

  defined as above is a coherent risk measure.[2]

Acceptance set

edit

The acceptance set for the superhedging price is the negative of the set of values of a self-financing portfolio at the terminal time. That is

 .[citation needed]

Subhedging price

edit

The subhedging price is the greatest value that can be paid so that in any possible situation at the specified future time you have a second portfolio worth less or equal to the initial one. Mathematically it can be written as  . It is obvious to see that this is the negative of the superhedging price of the negative of the initial claim ( ). In a complete market then the supremum and infimum are equal to each other and a unique hedging price exists.[3] The upper and lower bounds created by the subhedging and superhedging prices respectively are the no-arbitrage bounds, an example of good-deal bounds.[4][5]

Dynamic superhedging price

edit

The dynamic superhedging price has conditional risk measures of the form:

 

where   denotes the essential supremum. It is a widely shown result that this is time consistent.[6]

References

edit
  1. ^ "Dynamic Replication" (PDF). p. 3. Retrieved July 22, 2010.
  2. ^ Follmer, Hans; Schied, Alexander (October 8, 2008). "Convex and Coherent Risk Measures" (PDF). Retrieved July 22, 2010. {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  3. ^ Lei (Nick) Guo (August 23, 2006). "Pricing and hedging in incomplete markets" (PDF). pp. 10–17.
  4. ^ John R. Birge (2008). Financial Engineering. Elsevier. pp. 521–524. ISBN 978-0-444-51781-4.
  5. ^ Arai, Takuji; Fukasawa, Masaaki (2011). "Convex risk measures for good deal bounds". arXiv:1108.1273v1 [q-fin.PR].
  6. ^ Penner, Irina (2007). "Dynamic convex risk measures: time consistency, prudence, and sustainability" (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on July 19, 2011. Retrieved August 28, 2011. {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)