Lorenz curve
This article needs additional citations for verification. (May 2023) |
In economics, the Lorenz curve is a graphical representation of the distribution of income or of wealth. It was developed by Max O. Lorenz in 1905 for representing inequality of the wealth distribution.
The curve is a graph showing the proportion of overall income or wealth assumed by the bottom x% of the people, although this is not rigorously true for a finite population (see below). It is often used to represent income distribution, where it shows for the bottom x% of households, what percentage (y%) of the total income they have. The percentage of households is plotted on the x-axis, the percentage of income on the y-axis. It can also be used to show distribution of assets. In such use, many economists consider it to be a measure of social inequality.
The concept is useful in describing inequality among the size of individuals in ecology[1] and in studies of biodiversity, where the cumulative proportion of species is plotted against the cumulative proportion of individuals.[2] It is also useful in business modeling: e.g., in consumer finance, to measure the actual percentage y% of delinquencies attributable to the x% of people with worst risk scores. Lorenz curves were also applied to epidemiology and public health, e.g., to measure pandemic inequality as the distribution of national cumulative incidence (y%) generated by the population residing in areas (x%) ranked with respect to their local epidemic attack rate.[3]
Explanation
[edit]Data from 2005.
Points on the Lorenz curve represent statements such as, "the bottom 20% of all households have 10% of the total income."
A perfectly equal income distribution would be one in which every person has the same income. In this case, the bottom N% of society would always have N% of the income. This can be depicted by the straight line y = x; called the "line of perfect equality."
By contrast, a perfectly unequal distribution would be one in which one person has all the income and everyone else has none. In that case, the curve would be at y = 0% for all x < 100%, and y = 100% when x = 100%. This curve is called the "line of perfect inequality."
The Gini coefficient is the ratio of the area between the line of perfect equality and the observed Lorenz curve to the area between the line of perfect equality and the line of perfect inequality. The higher the coefficient, the more unequal the distribution is. In the diagram on the right, this is given by the ratio A/(A B), where A and B are the areas of regions as marked in the diagram.
Definition and calculation
[edit]The Lorenz curve is a probability plot (a P–P plot) comparing the distribution of a variable against a hypothetical uniform distribution of that variable. It can usually be represented by a function L(F), where F, the cumulative portion of the population, is represented by the horizontal axis, and L, the cumulative portion of the total wealth or income, is represented by the vertical axis.
The curve L need not be a smoothly increasing function of F, For wealth distributions there may be oligarchies or people with negative wealth for instance.[4]
For a discrete distribution of Y given by values y1, ..., yn in non-decreasing order ( yi ≤ yi 1) and their probabilities the Lorenz curve is the continuous piecewise linear function connecting the points ( Fi, Li ), i = 0 to n, where F0 = 0, L0 = 0, and for i = 1 to n:
When all yi are equally probable with probabilities 1/n this simplifies to
For a continuous distribution with the probability density function f and the cumulative distribution function F, the Lorenz curve L is given by: where denotes the average. The Lorenz curve L(F) may then be plotted as a function parametric in x: L(x) vs. F(x). In other contexts, the quantity computed here is known as the length biased (or size biased) distribution; it also has an important role in renewal theory.
Alternatively, for a cumulative distribution function F(x) with inverse x(F), the Lorenz curve L(F) is directly given by:
The inverse x(F) may not exist because the cumulative distribution function has intervals of constant values. However, the previous formula can still apply by generalizing the definition of x(F): where inf is the infimum.
For an example of a Lorenz curve, see Pareto distribution.
Properties
[edit]A Lorenz curve always starts at (0,0) and ends at (1,1).
The Lorenz curve is not defined if the mean of the probability distribution is zero or infinite.
The Lorenz curve for a probability distribution is a continuous function. However, Lorenz curves representing discontinuous functions can be constructed as the limit of Lorenz curves of probability distributions, the line of perfect inequality being an example.
The information in a Lorenz curve may be summarized by the Gini coefficient and the Lorenz asymmetry coefficient.[1]
The Lorenz curve cannot rise above the line of perfect equality.
A Lorenz curve that never falls beneath a second Lorenz curve and at least once runs above it, has Lorenz dominance over the second one.[5]
If the variable being measured cannot take negative values, the Lorenz curve:
- cannot sink below the line of perfect inequality,
- is increasing.
Note however that a Lorenz curve for net worth would start out by going negative due to the fact that some people have a negative net worth because of debt.
The Lorenz curve is invariant under positive scaling. If X is a random variable, for any positive number c the random variable c X has the same Lorenz curve as X.
The Lorenz curve is flipped twice, once about F = 0.5 and once about L = 0.5, by negation. If X is a random variable with Lorenz curve LX(F), then −X has the Lorenz curve:
- L − X = 1 − L X (1 − F)
The Lorenz curve is changed by translations so that the equality gap F − L(F) changes in proportion to the ratio of the original and translated means. If X is a random variable with a Lorenz curve L X (F) and mean μ X , then for any constant c ≠ −μ X , X c has a Lorenz curve defined by:
For a cumulative distribution function F(x) with mean μ and (generalized) inverse x(F), then for any F with 0 < F < 1 :
- If the Lorenz curve is differentiable:
- If the Lorenz curve is twice differentiable, then the probability density function f(x) exists at that point and:
- If L(F) is continuously differentiable, then the tangent of L(F) is parallel to the line of perfect equality at the point F(μ). This is also the point at which the equality gap F − L(F), the vertical distance between the Lorenz curve and the line of perfect equality, is greatest. The size of the gap is equal to half of the relative mean absolute deviation:
See also
[edit]- Distribution (economics)
- Distribution of wealth
- Welfare economics
- Income inequality metrics
- Gini coefficient
- Hoover index (a.k.a. Robin Hood index)
- ROC analysis
- Social welfare (political science)
- Economic inequality
- Zipf's law
- Pareto distribution
- Mean deviation
- The Elephant Curve
References
[edit]- ^ a b Damgaard, Christian; Jacob Weiner (2000). "Describing inequality in plant size or fecundity". Ecology. 81 (4): 1139–1142. doi:10.1890/0012-9658(2000)081[1139:DIIPSO]2.0.CO;2.
- ^ Wittebolle, Lieven; et al. (2009). "Initial community evenness favours functionality under selective stress". Nature. 458 (7238): 623–626. Bibcode:2009Natur.458..623W. doi:10.1038/nature07840. PMID 19270679. S2CID 4419280.
- ^ Nguyen, Quang D.; Chang, Sheryl L.; Jamerlan, Christina M.; Prokopenko, Mikhail (2023). "Measuring unequal distribution of pandemic severity across census years, variants of concern and interventions". Population Health Metrics. 21 (17): 17. doi:10.1186/s12963-023-00318-6. PMC 10613397. PMID 37899455.
- ^ Li, Jie; Boghosian, Bruce M.; Li, Chengli (14 February 2018). "The Affine Wealth Model: An agent-based model of asset exchange that allows for negative-wealth agents and its empirical validation". arXiv:1604.02370v2.
{{cite journal}}
: Cite journal requires|journal=
(help) - ^ Bishop, John A.; Formby, John P.; Smith, W. James (1991). "Lorenz Dominance and Welfare: Changes in the U.S. Distribution of Income, 1967-1986". The Review of Economics and Statistics. 73 (1): 134–139. doi:10.2307/2109695. ISSN 0034-6535. JSTOR 2109695.
Further reading
[edit]- Lorenz, M. O. (1905). "Methods of measuring the concentration of wealth". Publications of the American Statistical Association. 9 (70). Publications of the American Statistical Association, Vol. 9, No. 70: 209–219. Bibcode:1905PAmSA...9..209L. doi:10.2307/2276207. JSTOR 2276207. S2CID 154048722.
- Gastwirth, Joseph L. (1972). "The Estimation of the Lorenz Curve and Gini Index". The Review of Economics and Statistics. 54 (3). The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 54, No. 3: 306–316. doi:10.2307/1937992. JSTOR 1937992.
- Chakravarty, S. R. (1990). Ethical Social Index Numbers. New York: Springer-Verlag. ISBN 0-387-52274-3.
- Anand, Sudhir (1983). Inequality and Poverty in Malaysia. New York: Oxford University Press. ISBN 0-19-520153-1.
External links
[edit]- WIID Archived 2011-03-13 at the Wayback Machine: World Income Inequality Database, a source of information on inequality, collected by WIDER (World Institute for Development Economics Research, part of United Nations University)
- glcurve: Stata module to plot Lorenz curve (type "findit glcurve" or "ssc install glcurve" in Stata prompt to install)
- Free add-on to STATA to compute inequality and poverty measures
- Free Online Software (Calculator) computes the Gini Coefficient, plots the Lorenz curve, and computes many other measures of concentration for any dataset
- Free Calculator: Online and downloadable scripts (Python and Lua) for Atkinson, Gini, and Hoover inequalities
- Users of the R data analysis software can install the "ineq" package which allows for computation of a variety of inequality indices including Gini, Atkinson, Theil.
- A MATLAB Inequality Package Archived 2008-10-04 at the Wayback Machine, including code for computing Gini, Atkinson, Theil indexes and for plotting the Lorenz Curve. Many examples are available.
- A complete handout about the Lorenz curve including various applications, including an Excel spreadsheet graphing Lorenz curves and calculating Gini coefficients as well as coefficients of variation.
- LORENZ 3.0 is a Mathematica notebook which draw sample Lorenz curves and calculates Gini coefficients and Lorenz asymmetry coefficients from data in an Excel sheet.